0% found this document useful (0 votes)
36 views

MRes Micro1 Production

The document summarizes production theory concepts including: 1) Production sets which represent all feasible production vectors and have properties like closedness, free disposal, and non-decreasing returns to scale. 2) The profit maximization problem which involves maximizing revenue subject to the production set constraints. This determines the supply function. 3) The cost minimization problem which involves minimizing costs subject to a production function constraint to determine output. This determines factor demand and the cost function. 4) Properties of the profit and cost functions including homogeneity, convexity, and how they relate through Hotelling's lemma and Shephard's lemma.

Uploaded by

Aarthi Shankar
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
36 views

MRes Micro1 Production

The document summarizes production theory concepts including: 1) Production sets which represent all feasible production vectors and have properties like closedness, free disposal, and non-decreasing returns to scale. 2) The profit maximization problem which involves maximizing revenue subject to the production set constraints. This determines the supply function. 3) The cost minimization problem which involves minimizing costs subject to a production function constraint to determine output. This determines factor demand and the cost function. 4) Properties of the profit and cost functions including homogeneity, convexity, and how they relate through Hotelling's lemma and Shephard's lemma.

Uploaded by

Aarthi Shankar
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 10

MWG Chap 5: Production

Review: undergraduate production theory


• explicit distinction between input and output
• For example, consider two input factors, L and K, and one output, Q.
• First, for output Q, derive C(Q) = minL,K wL + rK s.t. Q = f (L, K).
• The optimization condition for the cost minimization is
w
M RT SL,K = ,
r
i.e., the marginal rate of technological substitution between labor and capital
is equivalent to the ratio of wage and rent.
• Another way to look at the profit maximization is:

max pf (L, K) wL rK.


L,K

Then the first order conditions are:

p ⇥ M PL = w and p ⇥ M PK = r

Production Sets - a more general approach


There are L goods, some of which may be used as inputs to produce other
good(s). A production vector is a vector y 2 RL : Here negative coordinates repre-
sent inputs and the positive coordinates represent outputs. The set of all feasible
production vectors for a firm is known as the firm’s production set Y ⇢ RL : any
y 2 Y is possible and any y 62 Y is not.
The production set Y is taken as a primitive datum of the theory, which is deter-
mined primarily by technological constraints, but possibly also by legal restrictions
and contractual commitments.
Commonly imposed properties of production sets Y :
– Y is closed: for a converging sequence (y n ) 2 Y , limn!1 y n 2 Y .
– Possibility of inaction (shut-down): 0 2 Y .
– No free lunch: Y \ RL+ = {0}.
– Free disposal: y 2 Y and y 0  y imply y 0 2 Y .
Given these properties, we may conveniently represent Y as consisting of vectors y
assuming non-positive values of F : RL ! R, called the transformation function,
with the property that the boundary points of Y assume 0.

16
• Production set Y := {y 2 RL : F (y)  0} ⇢ RL
• Transformation frontier: {y 2 RL : F (y) = 0}
• Marginal rate of transformation (along the transformation frontier):
@F
@yl
M RTl,k = @F
@yk

(M RT Sl,k is simply a renaming of M RTl,k of input l for input k in the special


case of a single-output, many-input technology.)
Other properties that may be assumed on Y :
– Irreversibility: y 2 Y & y 6= 0 ) y 2 / Y.
– Non-increasing returns to scale: y 2 Y ) ↵y 2 Y for ↵ 2 (0, 1).
– Non-decreasing returns to scale: y 2 Y ) ↵y 2 Y for ↵ 1.
– Constant returns to scale: y 2 Y ) ↵y 2 Y for ↵ 0.
– Additivity: y 2 Y and y 0 2 Y ) y + y 0 2 Y .
– Convexity: y 2 Y and y 0 2 Y ) ↵y + (1 ↵)y 0 2 Y for all ↵ 2 (0, 1).

17
Profit Maximization Problem

L
X
max p · y = p` y` s.t. y 2 Y (P M P )
y
`=1

• firms are price-takers where p = (p1 , · · · , pL ) 0.


• Y is nonempty and closed and satisfies the free disposal property.
• the solution y(p) is the supply function (or correspondence).
• the optimised value ⇡(p) := p · y(p) is the profit function.

Prop 5.C.1: Assume Y is closed and satisfies the free disposal property. Then
(i) ⇡(p) is homogeneous of degree 1 in p.
(ii) ⇡(p) is convex in p.
(iv) y(p) is homogeneous of degree 0 in p.
(v) If Y is convex, then y(p) is a convex set for all p; if Y is strictly convex, then
y(p) is single-valued (if nonempty).
(vi) Hotelling’s Lemma: If y(p̄) is single-valued, then ⇡(·) is di↵erentiable at p̄ and
r⇡(p̄) = y(p̄).
(vii) If y(·) is di↵erentiable at p̄, then Dy(p̄) = D2 ⇡(p̄) is a symmetric and positive
semi-definite matrix.

Proof. (i) and (iv) are straightforward.


(ii) Note that if z 2 y(↵p + (1 ↵)p0 ) for some ↵ 2 (0, 1), then
⇡(↵p + (1 ↵)p0 ) = ↵p · z + (1 ↵)p0 · z  ↵⇡(p) + (1 ↵)⇡(p0 )
where the equality follows from z 2 y(↵p + (1 ↵)p0 ) and the inequality follows
from the definition of ⇡. This verifies convexity of ⇡, i.e., ⇡(↵p + (1 ↵)p0 ) 
↵⇡(p) + (1 ↵)⇡(p0 ) for all p, p0 and ↵ 2 (0, 1).

18
(v) The first part follows because the objective function of (PMP) is linear.
To prove second part by contradiction, suppose that z, z 0 2 y(p). Then, as z 00 =
(z + z 0 )/2 is in the interior of Y , so is z 00 + ✏ej for sufficiently small ✏ where ej 2 RL
is a vector with 1 in some j-th coordinate such that pj > 0 and 0 in all other
coordinates. This would imply that p · (z 00 + ✏ej ) > y(p), contradicting z, z 0 2 y(p).
(vi) We prove this assuming all relevant di↵erentiability. Di↵erentiating the
identity F (y(p)) = 0 wrt pj , we get
X @yi ⇣ @y @yL ⌘T ⇣ @y @yL ⌘T
1 1
Fi (y(p)) =0 , rF (y(p))· ,··· , =0 , p· ,··· , =0
i
@pj @pj @pj @pj @pj

where the second equivalence (,) follows because rF (y(p)) = p as the graph
above illustrates and is explained below. Then, di↵erentiating ⇡(p) = p · y(p) wrt
pj , we get

@⇡(p) ⇣ X @y ⌘ ⇣ @y @yL ⌘T
i 1
= pi + yj (p) = p · ,··· , + yj (p) = yj (p).
@pj i
@pj @pj @pj

This proves (vi).


Then, (ii) and (vi) imply (vii).

Why rF (y(p)) = p (assuming di↵erentiability)?


Proof. Take any point y on the transformation frontier. The tangent line (more
precisely, the tangent hyperplane) at y consists of points y 0 such that, as y is changed
to the direction of y 0 y by an infinitesimal amount, the rate with which F (·) changes
is 0, that is,

@F (y) 0 @F (y) 0 @F (y) 0


(y1 y1 ) + (y2 y2 ) + · · · + (yL yL ) = 0
@y1 @y2 @yL
() (F1 (y), · · · , FL (y)) · (y10 y1 , · · · , yL0 yL ) T = 0
() rF (y) · (y 0 y) = 0.

Therefore, rF (y) is perpendicular to the tangent hyperplane of F at y.


At y = y(p), py is maximised among all y 2 Y , which implies that p is per-
pendicular to the tangent plane of F at y(p). Therefore, rF (y(p)) and p are both
perpendicular to the same hyperplane, so that rF ((p)) = p. That > 0 fol-
lows because both F (y) and py increases as y moves “outward” direction from y(p)
perpendicular to the hyperplane.

19
Prop: [The law of supply] p· y 0.
Proof. Observe that py(p) py(p0 ) and p0 y(p0 ) p0 y(p). Thus,

py(p) p0 y(p) py(p0 ) p0 y(p0 ) () p · y(p) p · y(p0 ) 0.

Cost Minimization Problem - Single output case:


Let q = f (z) be the output level and w the input price vector. Then, the cost
minimization problem is:

min w · z s.t. f (z) q (CmP )


z 0

Note that this is identical to the consumer’s EmP (except that q has cardinal, instead
of ordinal, meaning).
Kuhn-Tucker condition is:
,
@f @f @f wi
 wi , with equality if zi > 0 ) M RT S = = .
@zi @zi @zj wj

Example: Consider two inputs and one output case. Along the iso-quant curve,
@f @f
f (z1 , z2 ) = q. Total-di↵erentiating, we derive @z 1
dz1 + @z 1
dz2 = dq. On the iso-quant
curve, dq = 0. Thus, we derive
,
dz2 @f @f
= .
dz1 dq=0 @z1 @z2

As a solution to CmP, we derive the conditional factor demand z(w, q), and we
then derive the cost function c(w, q) := w · z(w, q).
Prop 5.C.2:
1. c(w, q) is homogeneous of degree 1 in w and nondecreasing in q.
2. c(w, q) is concave in w.
3. Dw c(w, q) = z(w, q) : Shephard’s lemma
4. Dw z(w, q) = Dw2 c(w, q): symmetric, negative semidefinite.
5. If f (·) is homogeneous of degree 1 (i.e., constant return to scale), then c(w, q)
and z(w, q) are homogeneous of degree 1 in q.
6. If f (·) is concave, then c(w, q) is a convex function in q (i.e., M C increases in
q).

20
7. If the set {z 0 : f (z) q} is convex for every q, then the production set is
Y = {( z, q) : w · z c(w, q) for all w 0}.
8. If the set {z 0 : f (z) q} is convex, then z(w, q) is a convex set.
9. If the set {z 0 : f (z) q} is strictly convex, then z(w, q) is single-valued.

Profit Maximization Problem using Cost function

max p · q c(w, q) (P M P )
q 0

Prop P: If the producer is a price taker, the necessary first-order condition for the
solution q ⇤ is
@c(w, q ⇤ )
p , with equality if q ⇤ > 0. (5.C.6)
@q
If c(w, q) is convex in q, then the first-order condition (5.C.6) is also sufficient for
q ⇤ to be the firm’s optimal output level.
Example 5.C.1: Consider f (z1 , z2 ) = z1↵ z2 where ↵, > 0.

@f 1 ↵ z2 w1
F OC : = wi , i = 1, 2 ) ↵z1↵ 1 z2 = w1 , z1↵ z2 = w2 ) =
@zi z1 w2
✓ ◆ ✓ ◆ ↵+ ✓ ◆ ↵+↵
w1 1 ↵w2 1 w1
z(w, q) : q = z1↵ z1 ) z1 = q ↵+ , z2 = q ↵+
w2 ↵ w1 ↵w2
✓ ◆
1 ↵ ↵ ↵ ↵
) c(w, q) = w1 z1 + w2 z2 = q ↵+ ( ) ↵+ +( ) ↵+ w1 ↵+ w2 ↵+ .
⇣ ↵
⌘ ↵
For notational simplicity, define ✓ := ( ↵ ) ↵+ + ( ↵ ) ↵+ and (w1 , w2 ) := w1 ↵+ w2 ↵+ .
1
Then c(w, q) = q ↵+ ✓ (w1 , w2 ) and M C(q) is

@c(w, q) 1 1
1
= q ↵+ ✓ (w1 , w2 )
@q ↵+

which is increasing (constant, decreasing, resp.) in q if ↵ + < 1 (= 1, > 1, resp.).


(1) If ↵ + < 1 (DRS), then MC converges to 0 as q ! 0 and converges to 1
as q ! 1. Hence, there exists a unique optimal output level q ⇤ that solves (PMP),
characterised by the FOC:
✓ ◆ 1 ↵+↵
1 1
1 ⇤ p(↵ + )
p= q ↵+ ✓ (w1 , w2 ) ) q (p, w) =
↵+ ✓ (w1 , w2 )

21
This solution q ⇤ (p, w) is the firm’s supply function. Plugging q ⇤ (p, w) into the ob-
jective function of (PMP), we derive the firm’s profit function ⇡(p, w) = pq ⇤ (p, w)
c(w, q ⇤ (p, w)). Plugging q ⇤ (p, w) into the conditional factor demand, we derive (un-
conditional) factor demand zi (p, w).
(2) If ↵ + = 1 (CRS), then MC is a constant. If this is equal to p, any output
level is optimal with profit of 0. If this is larger than p then q = 0 is optimal.
Otherwise, there is no optimal output level, because producing more increases the
profit.
(3) If ↵ + > 1 (IRS), then MC converges to 0 as q ! 1. This means that the
profit increases without bound as q ! 1, so again there is no optimal output level.

Short-run and Long-run


– Short-run means a short span of time for which some inputs may not be
changed.
– Long-run means a long enough span of time for which any input may be
changed.
– Long-run cost function is a low envelope of short-run cost functions.
“Le Chatelier Principle”: The long-run response of a firm’s supply to a price
change is larger than the short-run response.
Proof. Consider a benchmark price p⇤ and the optimal long-run supply y(p⇤ ).
Let the first input, z1 , be fixed at z1⇤ = z1 (p⇤ ) in the short run. When the price
changes to p from p⇤ , let y(p) denote the long-run optimised supply for the changed
price, while y(p|z1⇤ ) denote the short-run optimised supply for the changed price.
We need to show that
dy(p) dy(p|z1⇤ )
() y 0 (p⇤ ) y 0 (p⇤ |z1⇤ ) 0.
dp p=p⇤ dp p=p⇤

As y(p) solves maxy py c(y), the first order condition is that p c0 (y) = 0 when
y = y(p). Hence, by di↵erentiating ⇡(p) = py(p) c(y(p)) with respect to p, we get

d⇡(p)
= y(p) + py 0 (p) c0 (y(p))y 0 (p) = y(p).
dp

(Note that this is Hotelling’s Lemma.) Similarly, as the short-run solution y(p|z1⇤ )
solves maxy py c(y|z1⇤ ), the first order condition is that p c0 (y|z1⇤ ) = 0 when

22
y = y(p|z1⇤ ). Hence, by di↵erentiating ⇡ S (p|z1⇤ ) = py(p|z1⇤ ) c(y(p|z1⇤ )|z1⇤ ) with
respect to p, we get

d⇡ S (p|z1⇤ )
= y(p|z1⇤ ) + py 0 (p|z1⇤ ) c0 (y(p|z1⇤ )|z1⇤ )y 0 (p|z1⇤ ) = y(p|z1⇤ ).
dp
Thus, we need to show
⇣ d2 ⇡(p) d2 ⇡ S (p|z1⇤ ) ⌘
y 0 (p⇤ ) y 0 (p⇤ |z1⇤ ) = 0. (1)
dp2 dp2 p=p⇤

Given any p, ⇡(p) denotes the long-run optimised profit level and ⇡ S (p|z1 ) de-
notes the short-run optimised profit level when the first input is fixed at z1 . Thus,
by definition,
⇡(p) = ⇡ S (p|z1 (p)) ⇡ S (p|z1⇤ )
where z1 (p) is the optimal amount of first input in the long-run. Then,

⇡(p|p⇤ ) := ⇡(p) ⇡ S (p|z1⇤ ) = ⇡ S (p|z1 (p)) ⇡ S (p|z1⇤ ) 0, equality when p = p⇤ .

I.e. ⇡(p|p⇤ ) achieves minimum at p⇤ . Thus,

d ⇡(p|p⇤ ) d2 ⇡(p|p⇤ )
= 0 and 0.
dp p=p⇤ dp2 p=p⇤

This proves (1) because

d2 ⇡(p|p⇤ ) ⇣ d2 ⇡(p) d2 ⇡ S (p|z1⇤ ) ⌘


= .
dp2 p=p⇤ dp2 dp2 p=p⇤

23
Monopoly Pricing: (Section 12.B) Let x(p) be the market demand function which
we assume is downward sloping. The inverse demand function is p(·) = x 1 (·) that
associates for each output level a price at which the entire output is demanded.
Then, the monopolist’s problem is
max p(q)q c(q) (12.B.2)
q 0

Under minor technical conditions, including di↵erentiability of p(·) and c(·), a ver-
sion of Prop P for a monopolist characterizes the interior solution q m as
p0 (q m )q m + p(q m ) = c0 (q m ), (12.B.4)
which states that the firm’s (private) marginal revenue equals the marginal cost.
As a benchmark, calculate the socially optimum production q o that maximizes
the total consumers surplus net of the production cost:
Z q̃
o
q solves max p(q)dq c(q̃) () p(q o ) = c0 (q o ) (SO)
q̃ 0

according to the FOC. Note that p(q) and c0 (q) are the “social marginal benefit”
and the “social marginal cost” of production. Since p0 (q) < 0 (i.e., social marginal
benefit decreases), provided that c0 (q) is non-decreasing in q, the FOC is also a
sufficient condition for social optimum. Hence, from comparing (12.B.4) and (SO),
we deduce that q m < q o [elaborate] and consequently, conclude (see a diagrammatic
illustration of (12.B.4) and (SO) in Figure 12.B.1):
• the monopoly price exceeds marginal cost;
• the monopoly output falls short of the socially optimum level;
• the social welfare is lower under monopoly, which is represented by the dead-
weight loss triangle.

Figure 12.B.1

24
The inefficiency in monopoly stems from the following fact: Increasing production
above q m increases social welfare because the willingness to pay for the additional
output exceeds the production cost, however this would take place at the expense
of the monopolist due to a lower price corresponding to a larger output.
Exercise 1.6: Suppose the demand function is x(p) = a bp and the monopolist’s
cost function is c(q) = cq where a, b, c > 0. Find the monopolist’s optimal quan-
tity (q m ) and price (pm ). What are the socially optimal output level (q o ) and the
corresponding price?

(Chapters in M-W-G summarized in this lecture on production: Sections 5.A and


5.C of Chap 5, and Section 12.B of Chap 12 — Read carefully and absorb fully.)

Problem Set #1
(due date to be determined)

Q1: Q1 of Exercise questions on consume theory (Lecture notes, p14)


Q2: part (3) of Q2 of Exercise questions on consume theory.
Q3: 3.D.6 from MWG.
Q4: part (b) of 5.C.9 from MWG, where p is output price and w = (w1 , w2 ) is
input price vector.
Q5: 5.C.13 from MWG.

Additional Exercises in M-W-G (not to be handed in): 5.C.7. 5.C.9, 5.C.10, 12.B.2,
12.B.6, 12.B.7, 12.B.8, 12.B.9.

25

You might also like